Explaining the US labour force participation problem
Please note that throughout this post I take "labour force" to mean people aged 15-64, which is consistent with OECD definitions. I exclude over-65s and children under 15.
Patrick Artus at Natixis notes that there is something “odd”
about the US’s economic recovery. The labour force participation rate (or rather "activity" rate, as I am using OECD definitions) is
falling for both men and women.
The male activity rate has been falling for a long time. But until about 2000, the female activity rate was rising sharply. It levelled off during the 2000s and is now falling.
Falling activity rates are often blamed on the long-term unemployed giving up the quest for work. And indeed the US does have a long-term unemployment problem at the moment:
But of course, measures of the long-term unemployed tell us nothing at all about discouraged demand: if they are reported as “unemployed”, then they are counted IN the active labour force. If anything, the fact that that US is still reporting high levels of long-term unemployed, five years after the recession, suggests that discouraged demand is NOT the principal cause of the declining activity rate.
This is something of a pity. If the declining activity rate were due to long-term unemployed giving up looking for work, we might expect
that it would improve once jobs became easier to find. A cyclical fall in the activity rate is far easier to address than a secular decline.
Research by Alicia Munnell, director of the Center for Retirement Research at Boston College, has suggested that the falling participation rate is a secular decline due to demographic changes. The story
goes that labour force participation peaked in 2000, then has declined since
and is now on a downward trajectory as baby boomers retire and leave the labour
force. In a recent speech, the Fed’s James Bullard appeared to support this argument. (Update: To be fair to both, they include over-65s in their definitions. I've explained at the end of this post why I exclude over-65s).
But Natixis’s Patrick Auter has a different explanation (my emphasis):
Despite the decline in unemployment and the growth in employment and activity, the participation rate continues to decline in the United States, which is mainly due to the decline in activity of the young, not older workers as is often thought.
Using the data from the OECD’s
Employment Review quoted by Natixis (op.cit.), I have charted activity rates for
men by age decile:
There is a striking fall in the activity rate for the youngest men, together with a RISE in the activity rate of the oldest cohort.
The same features show up even more strikingly in the female
chart:
Taking out the oldest and youngest deciles from both charts gives us the activity rates by decile for prime-aged men and women:
Men
Women
There is evidence of a small cyclical fall in the activity rate on the men’s chart, which is beginning to reverse, at least for younger men. The women’s chart also seems to show slight cyclical variation. But there does not seem to be a crisis of activity among prime working-age Americans. There is no “outbreak of idleness” among men, as Charles Murray has suggested. And there is no outbreak of single mums depending on state benefit, either: the female cohort whose participation rate is falling the most is 45-54 – hardly the age of single parenthood.
Nor is there any evidence to support the argument that the activity rate is declining because baby boomers are retiring. On the contrary, it seems that baby boomers are NOT retiring: activity rates for older men and women are rising. The group whose activity rate IS falling – considerably – is young people.
But this is not due to idle young people living off their
parents, lounging around on street corners and smoking weed. This
chart from the OECD shows that the participation rate of young people aged
15-20 in education has risen 10% since 1995:
And the participation rate of young people aged 20-29 in education has risen about 6%:
According to the National Center for Education’s report “The Condition of Education 2012”, participation in education and training has risen hugely, particularly among young adults (my emphasis):
The enrollment rates for 7- to 13-year-olds and 14- to 15-year-olds were generally higher than the rate for 16- to 17-year-olds, but the rate for 16- to 17-year-olds did increase from 90 percent in 1970 to 96 percent in 2010….
Young adults ages 18–19 are typically transitioning into college education or the workforce. Between 1970 and 2010, the overall enrollment rate (including enrollment at both the secondary level and the college level) for young adults ages 18–19 increased from 48 to 69 percent. During this period, the enrollment rate for 18- and 19-year-olds at the secondary level increased from 10 to 18 percent, while the rate at the college level rose from 37 to 51 percent. Between 2000 and 2010, the college enrollment rate increased from 45 to 51 percent.
Adults ages 20–34 who are in school are usually enrolled in college or graduate school. Between 1970 and 2010, the enrollment rate for adults ages 20–24 increased from 22 to 39 percent, and the rate for adults ages 25–29 increased from 8 to 15 percent. The enrollment rate for adults ages 30–34 increased from 4 percent in 1970 to 8 percent in 2010. Between 2000 and 2010, the enrollment rate for adults ages 20–24 increased from 32 to 39 percent; for adults ages 25–29, it increased from 11 to 15 percent; and for adults ages 30–34, it increased from 7 to 8 percent.
So it is education that is primarily causing the decline in working-age labour force activity. That is not to say that ageing baby boomers won't be a problem, nor that there may not be some discouraged demand - especially since it seems jobs are rather hard to come by. But if these effects exist. they are marginal compared to the loss of young people from the workforce due to education and training.
Patrick Artus comments that:
Patrick Artus comments that:
The decline in the participation rate casts doubt on the reality of the improvement in the labour market situation in the United States.
Is he right? Well, no. A better–educated workforce should
improve the quality of labour, even though it diminishes its quantity, particularly
among younger cohorts. And that would be a good thing both for business and
for labour.
Though of course, the available education may not be as valuable as people think.
UPDATE
Matthew B (@boes_ on Twitter) points out that I have excluded over-65s from my analysis, which necessarily invalidates the research findings that baby boomers are responsible for the falling participation rate. Indeed I have, because I am interested in why working-age participation is falling. We don't regard over-65s as "working age", any more than we regard children under 16 as "working age". It is in my view perverse to include over-65s in measures of labour force participation but not children under 16. And more to the point, it is a serious distortion.
Over-65s are by far the largest part of the non-working population, and their number is growing, both because of increasing longevity and because of the retirement of "baby boomers" (people born 1946-64). Their presence in measures of labour force non-participation dominates everything else. This means that other factors, such as those I am highlighting in this post, seem much less important. With over-65s in the picture, retiring baby boomers are indeed by far the most important reason for declining labour force participation. But when we exclude them - remembering that we do not expect them to be active labour force participants anyway - it becomes clear that there is a secular change going on: young people are delaying their entry to the workforce by studying for longer, and older people are delaying their planned exit from the workforce by working for longer. Both of these are to some extent forced by legislation: young people in many states now have to remain in education until they are 18, and the statutory retirement age is gradually rising.
I would like to clarify a point I made in the post which has caused some confusion since I am excluding over-65s. When I refer to "baby boomers NOT retiring", I am referring to those older people who would have retired earlier than their statutory retirement age but are choosing not to, perhaps because low interest rates mean their savings are not delivering the returns they expected. It's also worth noting that social security changes mean there is now a considerable disincentive for people aged 62-64 to retire early, since if they do they lose substantial parts of their social security. This may partly explain the rising participation rate of both men and women aged 61-64.
I looked at the decline in prime working-age participation as well as total working-age participation. I use the OECD measure of total labour force participation or "activity", so the total working-age labour force is 15-64. But prime working-age labour force is as defined in the United States, namely 25-54. My conclusion is that the decline in total working-age labour force participation is a mainly secular trend driven by delayed entry to and exit from the workforce as described above. But the current decline in prime working-age labour force participation is almost entirely cyclical and can be expected to correct itself as conditions improve.
It should be apparent that if I had left over-65s in my analysis, it would not have been possible for me to reach these conclusions. Therefore I defend my decision to exclude them.
Related reading:
How to better understand labour force participation, eventually - FT Alphaville
Is America working? - Pieria
What accounts for the decrease in the labour force participation? - Atlanta Fed
UPDATE
Matthew B (@boes_ on Twitter) points out that I have excluded over-65s from my analysis, which necessarily invalidates the research findings that baby boomers are responsible for the falling participation rate. Indeed I have, because I am interested in why working-age participation is falling. We don't regard over-65s as "working age", any more than we regard children under 16 as "working age". It is in my view perverse to include over-65s in measures of labour force participation but not children under 16. And more to the point, it is a serious distortion.
Over-65s are by far the largest part of the non-working population, and their number is growing, both because of increasing longevity and because of the retirement of "baby boomers" (people born 1946-64). Their presence in measures of labour force non-participation dominates everything else. This means that other factors, such as those I am highlighting in this post, seem much less important. With over-65s in the picture, retiring baby boomers are indeed by far the most important reason for declining labour force participation. But when we exclude them - remembering that we do not expect them to be active labour force participants anyway - it becomes clear that there is a secular change going on: young people are delaying their entry to the workforce by studying for longer, and older people are delaying their planned exit from the workforce by working for longer. Both of these are to some extent forced by legislation: young people in many states now have to remain in education until they are 18, and the statutory retirement age is gradually rising.
I would like to clarify a point I made in the post which has caused some confusion since I am excluding over-65s. When I refer to "baby boomers NOT retiring", I am referring to those older people who would have retired earlier than their statutory retirement age but are choosing not to, perhaps because low interest rates mean their savings are not delivering the returns they expected. It's also worth noting that social security changes mean there is now a considerable disincentive for people aged 62-64 to retire early, since if they do they lose substantial parts of their social security. This may partly explain the rising participation rate of both men and women aged 61-64.
I looked at the decline in prime working-age participation as well as total working-age participation. I use the OECD measure of total labour force participation or "activity", so the total working-age labour force is 15-64. But prime working-age labour force is as defined in the United States, namely 25-54. My conclusion is that the decline in total working-age labour force participation is a mainly secular trend driven by delayed entry to and exit from the workforce as described above. But the current decline in prime working-age labour force participation is almost entirely cyclical and can be expected to correct itself as conditions improve.
It should be apparent that if I had left over-65s in my analysis, it would not have been possible for me to reach these conclusions. Therefore I defend my decision to exclude them.
Related reading:
How to better understand labour force participation, eventually - FT Alphaville
Is America working? - Pieria
What accounts for the decrease in the labour force participation? - Atlanta Fed
"A better–educated workforce should improve the quality of labour... And that would be a good thing both for business and for labour."
ReplyDeleteI find this statement to be a bit too sanguine.
If the demand for labor is constrained by non-educational factors, education will just result in a better-educated unemployment line.
http://www.asymptosis.com/is-the-elasticity-of-labor-demand-at-zero.html#comment-2743
(I note that even Nick Rowe in the comments nods approvingly at this S/D diagram.)
If for instance, labor demand is constrained by secular stagnation in demand for goods and services, caused by extreme concentrations of wealth and income...
Steve,
ReplyDeleteYes, agreed. I discuss that in the Pieria post to which I link in the final line of this post.
Brick says
ReplyDeleteI would pretty much agree, except that I think much as the choices and opportunities for the less well off have declined so have the choices and opportunities for todays youth. There is not an abundance of aprenticeships, very few firms are sponsoring college education and if you cannot get a job choices are limited.
Further education is not all about university education, there are higher education establishments for vocational training. Part of the problem is that so many jobs have new regulations detailing which qualifications (think NVQ'S) or exams (think electricians having to pass an exam in the latest regulations every year) which you need to pass to work in a particular field.
By limiting young peoples choices, Education costs have been shifted to individuals.